Mish's Global Economic Trend Analysis |
- Men Will be Boys: Tit for Tat; Honor is the Paramount Concern; Honor for Honor
- Pettis Proposes Savings Glut and Income Inequality are Source of Global Imbalances; Mish vs. Pettis: I Respectfully Disagree
- Missing the Boat on Bitcoin Ownership; Theoretical Question Regarding Bitcoin Theft
Men Will be Boys: Tit for Tat; Honor is the Paramount Concern; Honor for Honor Posted: 17 Mar 2014 06:52 PM PDT Ohh.. Ahhh.. Oh ... Obama trumped up his response to the Russia takeover of Crimea with actions and threats of further actions. The New York Times posted Obama's Statement on New Sanctions Against Russia. I will spare you the sap of Obama's address. But interested parties can see US sanction fact sheet here: Ukraine-Related Sanctions. Are Sanctions Enough? Fox News asks Is it enough? Obama imposes sanctions on Russian officials over Crimea. Faced with calls for a swift and stern reaction to Russia's threatened annexation of Crimea, President Obama wielded his executive pen Monday morning, slapping seven in Vladimir Putin's inner circle -- but not the Russian president himself -- with sanctions freezing their U.S. assets.Whenever you are looking for war-mongering sap, rest assured McCain is the number one place to look. Short of launching an all-out military attack on Russia, nothing could appease McCain. Russian Deputy PM Laughs at Obama's Sanctions In response to sanctions a Russian Deputy PM Laughs at Obama's Sanctions. Russia's deputy prime minister laughed off President Obama's sanction against him today asking "Comrade @BarackObama" if "some prankster" came up with the list.Honor for Honor This is a rare case of US-Russia "honor for honor". Not only is Vladislav Surkov honored, so is senator John McCain. McCain Honored Please consider the Daily Beast report Russia Will Sanction U.S. Senators Putin is set to respond to Obama's sanctions of Russian officials with his own list. Several U.S. Senators and officials will be banned from visiting Russia, including Sen. Dick Durbin.There you have it. McCain is honored and so is Vladislav Surkov. Will Sanction Stupidity End Now? Will the stupidity end with "honor for honor"? Let's hope so, but I doubt it. McCain and his war-mongering consortium will pressure Obama for more sanctions. If Obama obliges, Russia will respond "tit for tat". Freeze Russian assets in the US and Russia will freeze US assets in Russia. Hmmm. What country do you think will fare worse in that trade? But what if Russia cuts off Europe's supply of natural gas? Men Will be Boys Clearly we cannot concern ourselves with such things as a European gas shutoff. After all, it's Europe at risk, not the US. More importantly, we all know "honor is the paramount concern". The saying goes "boys will be boys". I propose "men will be boys". It's a matter of honor. Mike "Mish" Shedlock http://globaleconomicanalysis.blogspot.com |
Posted: 17 Mar 2014 12:52 PM PDT Michael Pettis at China Financial Markets taught me much of what I know about global trade. I am very appreciative. I tend to agree with most of his views. I recommended his book "Great Rebalancing", and still do. In a recent email, however, Pettis revives the "Global Savings Glut" thesis and I strongly disagree. This is a somewhat lengthy discussion, but an extremely important one. "Income Inequality" is a front-page topic so let's take a close look. From Pettis ... Reviving the "Underconsumption" SchoolMish: Despite the obvious casino-like structure of global equity and bond markets, the poker game analogy is an extremely poor one. From the wheel to the telegraph to the phone it took fewer and fewer people to produce the same amount of output. Today, a single farmer can produce as much wheat as 200 farmers at the turn of the century. Unlike a group of guys playing a winner-take-all poker game, the global economy does not have a fixed number of chips. Because of increasing productivity and technology improvements, the number of chips increases every year. That initial error in conjunction with equating debt to savings, cascades into a series of miscalculations by Pettis. Pettis continues. Rising income inequality reduces demand. It does so in two ways. First, it directly forces down the consumption share of GDP, and second, it reduces productive investment by reducing, as Eccles says, "the kind of effective demand for their products that would justify a reinvestment of their capital accumulations in new plants."Mish: Is the problem lack of wage growth, or something else? I suggest "something else". For starters, the Euro was structurally flawed (and still is) One cannot blame Germany for that. What about competition in general? Rising productivity by definition means more goods produced with fewer people. What does basic economics tell us about an increase of goods with constant demand? The answer of course is prices should fall. Did they? Nope. Central banks in particular, and the Fed in general strive for 2% annualized inflation. In practice, and until recently, central banks allowed inflation to overshoot that target. Worse yet, central banks also ignored asset bubbles, especially housing prices that were not directly accounted for in the CPI. In the case of China there were also restraints on wage growth relative to productivity growth – not so much a policy choice, I would argue, but a consequence of the huge number of underemployed rural workers in China – but there were at least two other very important transfers. First, China has had an undervalued currency ever since 1994, which acts as a spur to growth in the tradable goods sector by effectively taxing foreign imports (and notice, by the way, that something similar happens in Germany, which also has an "undervalued" euro in relationship to the "overvalued" euro of countries like Spain, Italy and France). This reduces the real value of household income as a share of GDP.Mish: I agree with Pettis regarding the huge transfer of wealth from savers to borrowers. However, I suggest the transfer is a direct result of central bank inflation policies, not a result of a savings glut. The squeezing of the household sectorMish: Here is the key point Pettis and others miss: "inflation is theft". By holding down interests rates, while massively increasing the money supply, central banks fostered malinvestments and stock market speculation, then bailed out the banks. Those actions effectively robbed savers of their money. To equate "theft by inflation" to a global savings glut is an enormous error. In any closed economy, savings is always equal to investment. This simple truth, which is true by definition, has very powerful implications.Mish: I am in agreement regarding the description of malinvestments that Pettis mentioned. To that I will add that the pool of real savings was transferred from savers to banks and other speculators. When the bubble burst, the banks were bailed out at the expense of savers. As far as I can work out there are really only three logical ways a transfer of wealth is consistent with no change in the total savings and consumption shares of GDP.Mish: I certainly agree it's only a "question of time" before we reach debt capacity constraints. And it's equally clear that ordinary households are dis-saving. Interestingly, the lower the interest rate, the longer the imbalance can continue before it all blows sky high again (which by the way explains the desire of the Fed to artificially suppress interest rates). My disagreement with Pettis stems from his belief the wealthy are over-saving. Up next is the crux of the debate as well as another fatal flaw in the arguments presented by Pettis. If the savings rate in one part of the economy rises, without an equivalent rise in investment the only way for the economy to balance is for savings elsewhere to decline, and this can happen either in the form of a (usually credit-backed) consumption binge, or in the form of rising unemployment. The first is unsustainable.Mish: Let me react with moral certainty and repugnance of the preceding paragraph. On March 10, Bloomberg reported Debt Exceeds $100 Trillion as Governments Binge. The amount of debt globally has soared more than 40 percent to $100 trillion since the first signs of the financial crisis as governments borrowed to pull their economies out of recession and companies took advantage of record low interest rates. The $30 trillion increase from $70 trillion between mid-2007 and mid-2013 compares with a $3.86 trillion decline in the value of equities to $53.8 trillion, according to the Bank for International Settlements and data compiled by Bloomberg. The jump in debt as measured by the Basel, Switzerland-based BIS in its quarterly review is almost twice the U.S. economy. To depict $100 trillion in debt ($30 trillion of it since mid-2007) as "savings glut" is preposterous. I will present a detailed explanation why after one more clip from Pettis. Pettis concludes ... Either the world has to embark on a surge in productive investment, or we need to reduce the income share of the state and of the rich, or we must accept that unemployment will stay high for many more years.Mish: Once again I react with moral certainty and repugnance of the preceding two paragraphs. In his arguments, not all of which are shown above, Pettis painstakenly and with great precision outlined a number of accounting identities (e.g. savings = investment) that step-by-step seem to indicate he is correct. Interestingly, I agree with all of his accounting identities in isolation. So how can Pettis be so wrong? To understand where Pettis misses the mark, we have to focus on an even more basic accounting question regarding the nature of savings. What is Saving? Accounting Identity: Savings = Production Minus Consumption This is a fundamental economic law: You cannot consume what you don't produce. Sure, for periods of time you can consume that which is saved, but you cannot eat three loaves of bread if only two were ever produced. Saving by definition, is what remains after consumption. Is not more production a good thing? Of course it is. Increased production lowers costs and raises standards of living (at least it should, in the absence of central bank and government intervention). Money and Savings It is impractical for the baker to save loaves of bread for next year he does not want today. Perhaps he wants a pair of shoes instead of extra bread. But finding a shoemaker who wants bread is a problem. Perhaps the shoemaker wants apples, not bread. Money came into existence for precisely this reason. And where gold has been available, gold has always been used as money. It is scarce, stable, divisible, malleable, and pretty. Gold cannot be conjured into existence; it has to be mined. Dollars vs. Gold In contrast to gold, trillions and trillions of dollars have been fabricated out of thin air. Pettis makes an assumption that those dollars represent "savings". Let me ask Pettis a simple question: What was produced? The answer of course is nothing. And if nothing was produced, nothing can possibly be saved! The hoard of "savings" that Pettis wants to distribute is not really "savings" at all but rather money-substitutes fabricated for the sole benefit of already wealthy asset-holders at the expense of everyone else. Mauldin Misses the Boat as Well John Mauldin has written a series of articles recently on the subject of income inequality. In his latest Thoughts From the Frontline on Inequality and Opportunity Mauldin states ... If we want to do something about income inequality, perhaps we should think about the data that shows the remarkable correlation between education, educational opportunity, and income. ... the causes of income inequality are more difficult to come by than are the simple correlation analyses presented in many academic and political policy papers offered by various advocates in support of their personal policy choices (both conservative and liberal). I suggest to both Pettis and Mauldin that it is useless to complain about income inequality unless one also complains about the cause of it. The cause is not "difficult to come by" as Mauldin states. Nor is the cause an excess of savings. Here are some of the real causes. Causes of Income Inequality
None of the above remotely has anything to do with a "savings glut". There was no "savings glut" in 1933 and there sure isn't one today. Ironically, it was the explosion of debt, not the lack of savings that fueled the Great Depression and the Global Financial crisis. Margin debt and speculation soared in the late 1920s and is at an all-time high again now. Only by confusing the expansion of credit and money printed out of thin air with savings, can one propose a "savings glut" thesis. Realistically, debt does not equal savings and credit is not the same as money. To suggest, as Pettis does, that "excess thrift is a much more serious problem than insufficient thrift" is ridiculous. "Excess Thrift" Implies Two Falsehoods
Why does it imply the latter? The answer stems from the identity: Savings = Production Minus Consumption. In the absence of central bank and government manipulation, excess production will not last long. Goods will spoil or prices will fall. Malinvestment does not happen to any significant degree because unproductive businesses quickly fail. Competition ensures growth of supply and growth of jobs. In a free market society, real (inflation adjusted) wages would rise, even if nominal wages didn't. And that is precisely why the minimum wage debate is so wrongly focused. Falling prices and rising production raises standards of living. More people than ever before can consume goods because prices drop. When people get more for their money, standards of living rise. Then, what's left is saved. That savings is money available for future investments. There is no such thing as excess saving. It only appears that way when the Fed (central banks in general) distort price signals causing, speculation, rising asset prices, and malinvestment in unproductive assets. Mish Model on Cause of Income Inequality
Other factors enter the equation, notably transfers from ordinary taxpayers to public union pensioners. Also, bad ideas brought about by corrupt politicians on the take influences the picture, but central banks and fractional reserve lending, not wealthy hoarders are at the root of the problem. Much of this originates from one astonishingly bad idea, that falling prices are a bad thing. Note that increased production should lead to falling prices and rising standards of living. But central banks are hell-bent on preventing price deflation. To do that, they increase money supply. The money has no productive use. So it goes into speculation, bailouts, and malinvestments. Prices don't fall as they should. This punishes savers for the benefit of asset holders. Stock prices soar, and CEOs pay themselves massive amounts of stock options, a form of shareholder dilution. Countrywide Financial CEO Angelo Mozilo cashed out $1 billion in stock options over the years while driving the company into the ground. Does that really constitute a "savings glut" or is it something more like Fed-sponsored fraudulent conveyance of wealth? For further discussion of the one "astonishingly bad idea" that is a fundamental driver of income inequality, please see Monetarism, Abenomics, QE, and Minimum Wage Proposals: One Bad Idea Leads to Another, and Another Mike "Mish" Shedlock http://globaleconomicanalysis.blogspot.com |
Missing the Boat on Bitcoin Ownership; Theoretical Question Regarding Bitcoin Theft Posted: 17 Mar 2014 09:15 AM PDT I recently came across a pair of articles that make a case that bitcoins are not money but property. OK so what? Bob Lawless on Credit Slips discusses an alleged problem in Is UCC Article 9 the Achilles Heel of Bitcoin? Yves Smith at Naked Capitalism commented on the above. Yves' take: Is UCC Article 9 Going to Kill the Use of Bitcoin by US Businesses? Yves states ... Here is the layperson recap. If anyone takes Bitcoins from a business that has a blanket lien (and you as someone dealing with that business won't know the state of their finances) and that business gets in trouble, the bank can go after any current holder of Bitcoins that have passed through that business' accounts. This is not the case with money because Bitcoin is considered to be property under the UCC, not money. As the post stresses, "money". ... Bitcoin is property, and when you exchange the property of a business (its goods, like its doughnuts or other inventory for sale) for other property, like your Bitcoins, the next person who takes the Bitcoins (now regarded as property of the bakery) has any blanket liens of the bakery attach to those Bitcoins. Fundamental Error in Logic I believe Yves and Lawless made a fundamental error in logic. Once the bakery transfers those bitcoins to another person or corporation, the bitcoins are no longer property of the bakery. I do not believe any court of law would accept an argument the bakery has any rights to bitcoins it used to make purchases. And if the bakery has no right to those bitcoins then it is illogical to propose lien holders on the bakery have any right to them. I had an email exchange with Pater Tenebrarum at Acting Man over this issue. Pater writes, and I agree ... "Legally it should not matter whether the bakery pays a supplier with money or enters into a 'barter' arrangement (by paying with bitcoin). It is a payment either way. Moreover, the bakery could also first sell the bitcoin for money. Then it has delivered goods and accepted bitcoin in a 'barter' transaction for them, and the bitcoin have taken the place of their stock of salable goods. If we regard bitcoin legally as non-money, then the bakery is now not only a bakery, but has a bitcoin trading operation on the side. Only if it shifts bitcoins out illegally (e.g. after declaring bankruptcy, or shortly before, in an obvious attempt to fraudulently deprive creditors of attachable assets) will there be any further consequences." Theoretical Question Regarding Theft A far more interesting question does arise over theft. Consider stolen cars or paintings. If you buy a stolen car or painting. You have to return it. If you buy from a dealer, you can hold the dealer responsible. If you buy a stolen car or painting from someone who vanishes, you are out the money and the painting or the car. With that in mind, suppose someone stole your bitcoins from Mt.Gox or elsewhere. Unlike the bakery example above, those bitcoins are still your legitimate property. In the case of Mt.Gox, let's assume stolen coins. Let's also assume the thieves cashed out for untraceable US dollars. The next person who bought the bitcoins, bought stolen property. If one can determine the location of the stolen bitcoins, then lawsuits, and lots of them (over the rightful ownership) will be coming. Theoretically, if each bitcoin (and fraction thereof) had a unique number ID (and I believe it would have been possible to have set bitcoin up this way), then they could be traced. But if the bitcoin-blockchain was traceable in such a manner now, it would have already been done. If governments ever do go to digital currencies, I strongly suspect every cent will be traceable to someone at all times. Mike "Mish" Shedlock http://globaleconomicanalysis.blogspot.com |
You are subscribed to email updates from Mish's Global Economic Trend Analysis To stop receiving these emails, you may unsubscribe now. | Email delivery powered by Google |
Google Inc., 20 West Kinzie, Chicago IL USA 60610 |